Äîêóìåíò âçÿò èç êýøà ïîèñêîâîé ìàøèíû. Àäðåñ îðèãèíàëüíîãî äîêóìåíòà : http://e-journal.spa.msu.ru/uploads/vestnik/2004/vipusk_4._sentjabr_2004_g./nekipelov.pdf
Äàòà èçìåíåíèÿ: Sun Jul 6 06:48:26 2014
Äàòà èíäåêñèðîâàíèÿ: Sat Apr 9 23:51:22 2016
Êîäèðîâêà:
Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

Nekipelov D. A Two-Dimensional Criterion for Tax Policy Evaluation. A Primer from the Reform of Personal Income Taxation in Russia
Introduction. The evaluation of different tax systems per se is a very complicated problem. For example, if the Pareto criterion is used for this purpose the dimensionality of the problem becomes so big that it is not solvable even using modern technical tools. However, this comparison is essential and experts often rely on some verbal indicators to evaluate a tax reform proposal. We will concentrate here on the analysis of the policy, maximizing consumers' welfare. A real policy may pursue another aims, but in that case it would distort consumers' behavior leading to welfare loss. Ideally a policymaker would use the welfare function of the society for a comparison like that. However, to use the welfare function one needs to aggregate individual preferences that can also be unknown. Thus, in most cases it is only possible to assume that the welfare function exists. One can compare different functional forms for the welfare function, but in this case a policymaker does not have any consistent criteria for the evaluation of the given proposals. Moreover, given a certain specification it remains unclear how close this specification is to the true welfare function. In this paper it is shown that for a quite wide variety of welfare functions given some distribution of wealth in the population utilitarian welfare function with equal weight and an inequality index compose a sufficient statistics. Thus, the criterion for the comparison is twodimensional. Ranking of welfare functions is already a difficult task (see Shorrocks, (1987) and Sen, (1973)), so ranking of a two-dimensional characteristic is more difficult. A possible solution is to compare the characteristics with some standard characteristics. One can find it convenient to compare the situations with an imaginary no-tax case. This comparison will be incorrect, because that will be an attempt to compare an unconstraint Pareto ­ optimum with a situation which at best can be a constraint Pareto ­ optimum. Therefore, the result will depend on a particular welfare specification. The possible solution to this problem is to compare a current tax system with a system, maximizing a particular welfare function given a tax revenue constraint. This is done empirically in this paper. Statistical analysis of welfare functions. In this paper we consider a class of welfare functions that are mapping from the space of distributions of income to real numbers. In other words welfare functions assign a number to each particular income distribution function. The overview of some properties of such functions can be found in Myles (1995). Consider an integrable distribution function f. Then the aggregate welfare function W[f] can be taken to be positive. In reality, however, W is unknown. To uncover some of its properties from economic data we need to impose more properties on it. Suppose that W[·] has Gateaux derivatives up to the third order and denote them G1, G2, G3. Suppose also that the empirical distribution of incomes , for instance taken from a survey is known. Then we could expand it as . Here is some norm for the distance between the actual and the empirical distribution function. Assume also that is uniformly converging to f. This makes be converging to zero faster than other terms and leaves only the first two components in the expansion. Note that the empirical distribution function has a random character and so does the chosen norm. Now note that the corresponding Gateaux derivatives are non-random. The performed expansion allowed us to represent the stochastic welfare function as a linear combination of the measures of distribution.
© 2005

1


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

The notion of sufficient statistics has become common in the statistics literature. The relevant references include Lehman, (1959). Now consider the transition from the random variable W[ ] to random variable . Due to the presumed expansion the connection between them is quadratic. The corresponding Jacobian is linear. But this also makes this linear combination factor out of the probability distribution function, so that if the density function for is , then the density for W[ ] can be represented (in the limit) as ( )(G1+G2 1). This means that the linear combination is factored out from the density function for the welfare. By factorization theorem we can argue that the combination G1+G2 1 is statistics for the welfare function. Literally speaking sufficiency implies that the whole information about the is captured by those variables. This means that the represented combination of the empirical density function if it is uniformly converging in probability to the function. Take the norm the norm
1

a sufficient distribution norm of the true density . Then

be of an integral form that is

can be chosen to represent the weighted average of the distribution, while

the norm 2 can be chosen to represent the Gini coefficient. Thus, the combination of the weighed mean of income and the inequality index represent the sufficient statistics for the consumer's welfare. Ranking the welfare. Statistical analysis of welfare functions leads us to the conclusion that the sufficient statistics for capturing the welfare is two-dimensional. In this case two different after tax income distributions of the population can be incomparable because to be able to rank two distributions one needs to establish strict Lorenz domination of one distribution by the other (see Kakwani, (1956)). The proposed way of resolving this problem is to build classes of equivalent distributions. In this case the policymaker in the «worst» case of incomparable distributions can at least say that the one he or she is choosing is not the inferior one. A possible way of building these classes is to compare the current distribution of incomes with the one that arises when an optimal taxation is in effect. The optimum taxation here is presumed to maximize the welfare function given the revenue constraint for the government budget. The formal income taxation theory was introduced in the paper by Mirrles, (1977). Mirrles managed to reduce the welfare maximization problem to the problem of an optimal control. The derivations lead to the conclusion that the optimal marginal income tax rate is increasing as the elasticity of labor supply increases. Moreover, marginal tax rate increases as the productivity of workers is decreasing as well as the density of individuals with a given income level is decreasing. Formal analysis leads us to the expression for the optimum income tax rate given the parameters of the consumers. Such an analysis was performed for the United States by Saez, (1999). Therefore, to be able to construct reference level for welfare comparison we need to estimate the parameters of consumers' labor supply. Micro-analysis of labor supply. The analysis of labor supply in Russia has been made thoroughly since the extensive databases like RLMS became publicly available. Relevant literature includes Stillman, (2000), Sabirianova, (2000), Roshin and Razumova, (2002) and others. In these papers the RLMS database is found to be extensive and giving reasonable estimates for various individual parameters. In this paper we obtain the characteristics of the labor supply for different population groups to get the elasticities of labor supply with respect to a post tax wage. To get this dependence an hourly wage for RLMS respondents was calculated which was augmented with the aid of the Goskomstat data on regional price

© 2005

2


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

indices. The original sample was split into 4 and 20 parts according to the quantities of the hourly wage distribution. The rounds of RLMS were chosen to capture the effect of the reform of income taxation in the Russian Federation so only ninth and tenth rounds were used. The basic result of the reform is that the structure of labor supply has changed. As one can see from Table 1, labor force participation has decreased in the year 2001.
Table 1. The structure of employment in the rounds 9 and 10 in the RLMS sample

Year 2000 2001

Fraction of respondents having a job 49.94% 49.52%

Fraction of female respondents having a job 45.40% 45.94%

Fraction of male respondents having a job 55.91% 54.39%

The discrepancy in the figures is quite small and can be caused by some random increment in the sample. An important result is that the tendencies for the labor force participation for males and females are different. While the participation of females has risen by 0.54% the participation among males has dropped by 0.48%. The model for the estimation was taken to be a combination of linear and nonlinear models. The main dependence for the estimation is the dependence of the weekly hours of work from the hourly wage and household's individual parameters. The hourly wage in turn is taken from the supporting equation which is a standard Mincer wage equation with independent variables containing age, age squared and experience level. In addition the first step equation included binary variables representing having children younger than 5 years and between 5 and 17 years old, and the quality of parents' education. The main equation of the hours worked monthly was estimated in logarithms: , while wag equation takes the form: , where ­ coefficients, ­ random increments, - wage, predicted from the first step, Faminc ­ family income variable, AGE ­ age of RLMS respondent, EXP ­ work experience, INS ­ the variable, reflecting the possession of higher education, ­ the variable, reflecting marriage status. The first step equation can be motivated by the theory of human capital so that age and age squared reflect the return to human capital and diminishing returns of scale. The family and education variable reflect the dynamics of the human capital over time. The sample was split into 20 parts and for each labor supply equation was estimated. The presented graph represents the elasticity of labor supply as the logarithm of hourly wage is changing

© 2005

3


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

One can see that the elasticity of labor supply tends to increase on the interval of observation, but it is statistically insignificant for low wage levels. Therefore, labor supply of the males with a high income is the most elastic to wage changes. The labor supply of females is overall less elastic than the labor supply of males.

While this graph shows that the elasticity of labor supply tends to grow as the wage grows. However, in most cases the elasticity estimate is not significant which can imply that the labor supply of females is less sensitive with respect to the real wage. Therefore, it can be concluded that the labor supply of males and females has the property of increasing elasticity as the real wage increases. One can also notice very low estimates for the labor supply elasticity that can be caused by the legal constraints on the working day. This effect can be reduced if one considers secondary employment as well, but
© 2005

4


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

then some complications from taxation issues and interpretations of an hourly wage can occur. Inequality analysis. To analyze the connection between distributional and welfare impact of taxation it is necessary to determine the distributional characteristics of the taxation. It was shown above that the Gini index is a part of the sufficient statistics for the welfare function so it can be used to measure this distributional impact. For the construction of distributional impact the panel of RLMS respondents was matched with their individual characteristics relevant for the tax liabilities calculation. The built array of data was used to calculate the income of the respondents before taxes (assuming that the respondents were reporting their true post-tax income and all possible allowances and deductions were fully utilized for their actual tax payments). The considered taxes included the personal income tax and the payments to the non-budgetary funds that were supposed to be fully shifted towards the workers. This helped to calculate after-tax and post-tax wages for all working individuals. Consider the trends in inequality indices on the basis of 20 subsamples of the original RLMS sample. On the graph below one can see the dependence of the Gini coefficient from the logarithm of an hourly wage of RLMS male respondents for the year 2000.

Inequality indices are close up to the groups of males with a high income. One can also notice that as a wage becomes higher the inequality of wages becomes higher as well with the exception of the males with the lowest incomes. This tendency remains in effect for the sample of males in the year 2001.

© 2005

5


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

In this case no significant decrease in inequality for the males with a low income is observed. The trend in inequality for the females is the opposite from that of the males.

As one can see from the graph a steep decrease in inequality when the wage increases from the lowest to the median is followed by a small increase in inequality for the wages of the women with the highest wages. It is also possible to see that the difference between the inequality indices before and after taxes is small. In the year 2001 the decreasing trend in wage inequality for female subsample is not observed.

© 2005

6


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

While it is possible to argue that the inequality in the subsamples of females with higher wages is lower on average, this trend is unstable over the time. The inequality is smoothly increasing from the lowest to the average wage and is increasing when the wage is higher than average. The construction of welfare­maximizing marginal income tax rates. To construct reference level for the two-dimensional welfare comparisons we need to establish the parameters of the welfare-maximizing tax system. In this paper Mirrles' calculations were used to find the optimal marginal income tax rates. To simplify the computational procedure the utility functions of individuals were chosen to be separable with respect to consumption and leisure. This leads to the parameters of the optimal tax system. Mirrles' result implies that the marginal tax rates for the highest and the lowest wage individual should be zero. On the other hand, as the elasticity of labor supply goes down to zero the optimal tax rate can be set equal to 1 (as the individual is not distorted by high marginal tax rates). Thus, according to our estimates of labor supply elasticity, the optimal tax system for Russia should be based on complete smoothing of incomes for the most of the income distribution (i.e. withdrawing all income beyond the certain level). This result of course cannot be taken as a guide for a tax reform. Firstly, it is obtained assuming perfect tax administration without taking into account the behavioral response of individuals on the change in the tax rates by increased tax evasion. Secondly, administrative costs of collecting income tax with high marginal tax rates are not taken into account. Lastly, individual preferences over the level and quantity of offered public goods are not incorporated into considered utility functions. In particular, high marginal tax rates can lead to overproduction of public goods and will not be optimal. The constructed optimal income tax schedule was applied to the calculated pre-tax incomes of individuals in the RLMS sample. Calculation of welfare change due to taxation. In the previous paragraph the construction of inequality indices was discussed. The other component of the two­ dimensional criterion under consideration is the weighted average of individual welfares that represents the utilitarian welfare function. In this paper it is assumed that an individual utility is separable with respect to leisure and consumption. As a result the elasticity of compensated labor supply coincides with the uncompensated elasticity. This means that the estimates of the
© 2005

7


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

uncompensated elasticity obtained above remain applicable here. Standard ways of calculating the welfare change are appropriate here as appropriate normalization leads to the equivalence of leisure and consumption. The general task for the welfare change is to construct a reasonable estimate of the utility change for the economic agents. The value of the utility function itself has no meaning, so appropriate normalization is needed to make it comparable across individuals. Such normalization can be represented by the money-metric utility function. To obtain the appropriate welfare change for the simplest case let us consider an individual utility as a function of consumption (equal to the wage income wl for simplicity) and the utility of labor l: , then the change in the wage leads to the following change in the utility: . Using the . envelope theorem one can reduce this expression to: If we denote the income of the individual by y and the elasticity of labor supply with , the following expression can be obtained: . respect to the wage by The first term in this expansion represents the change in the utility level due to the change in the individual income. The second term shows the change due to the change in the labor-leisure choice. Particularly, if the change in the wage occurs due to the change in the tax rate, then the second term can be rewritten as: . The analog of this formula was used for the calculation of the welfare change for the transition from the optimal income taxation to the actual income taxation. The graph below represents the results of calculations of the welfare change in the sample during the transition from the optimal income taxation to the actual income taxation.

As one can see the distribution of welfare change is such that the main change occurs on the individuals with a high income. These fractions tend to grow with the income growth both in the year 2000 and the year 2001. One can see from the graph that in the year 2000 the wealthiest individuals had a relatively bigger welfare change then those in the year 2001. At the same time the fractions of the welfare change for the lower income individuals increase in the year 2001. Aside from the rather abstract consideration of the welfare at the current tax schedule and the optimal tax schedule it is possible to look at the welfare change during the tax reform
© 2005

8


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

in the year 2000. The graph below shows that the highest changes in the welfare due to the reform in the year 2000 are observed for the individuals with the highest income. The reform, on the other hand, resulted in the decrease in the marginal tax rates for the high wealth individuals, which leads us to the conclusion that the reform was welfare­improving with respect to the utilitarian welfare criterion. Moreover, the welfare increase is higher for the higher wage individuals.

Thus, this analysis points out that without regard to the incomparability of the welfare change distributions for the two years the tax reform has lead to the increase in the welfare if measured with the aid of the utilitarian criterion. The application of the two-dimensional criterion. To compare the situations before and after the tax reform in the year 2000 two indicators ­ the welfare change value (as compared to the optimal tax system) and the inequality index was assigned to each of the twenty subsamples. These characteristics correspond to the coordinates on the graph below.

© 2005

9


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

One can notice that the points for the year 2000 on average are located far from the origin (which corresponds to the optimal tax system). On the other hand the points for the year 2001 are located closer to the origin. To find out the difference between the two locations significantly the test for the mean comparison was performed. It shows that the locus of the points for the year 2001 is statistically closer to the origin than that of the points for the year 2000. This leads to the conclusion that the tax reform has led to the increase in the welfare of Russian working individuals according to the presented two-dimensional criterion. Conclusion and policy recommendations. This paper considered one way of reducing the dimensionality of the problem of welfare comparisons for different tax systems. It was proved that the utilitarian welfare function and the inequality index represent the sufficient statistics for a wide variety of welfare functions. Further it was argued that the comparison of the current tax system with the situation without taxes is not completely justified because it leads to the comparison of a constrained Pareto-optimum with an unconstrained one. The better criterion can be created by the comparison of the current tax schedule with the tax schedule leading to the constrained Pareto­optimum. A schedule like that was built on the basis of Mirrles' optimal taxation theory. The implementation of this criterion to the situation with the Russian tax reform in the year 2000 has led us to the conclusion that the tax reform was welfare­improving with respect to the built criterion. The constructed criterion can appear to be useful in the policy analysis because it allows to reduce significantly the arbitrary character of the choice between the «almost equivalent» tax rules. This criterion is applicable to the situations when the aim of the tax policy is the increase in the welfare of the individuals and it can be not relevant in the case of other policy objectives. However, as the maximization of the aggregate welfare is important in most cases it can be used as one of the additional characteristics for the analysis of a policy change.

© 2005

10


Public Management. Electronic journal Issue 4. 10 september 2004

References: 1. Atkinson, A.B., «Horizontal Equity and the Distribution of the Tax Burden», in «The Economics of Taxation», Aaron H. J., Boskin M.J. eds. 2. Auerbach A. J., «The Theory of Excess Burden and Optimal Taxation» / Handbook of Public Economics. ­ Vol.1 / Auerbach A.J., Feldstein M., eds. ­ North-Holland, 1987, pp. 61129. 3. Auerbach A. J., James R. H. Jr. «Taxation and Economic Efficiency». ­ NBER Working Paper #8181. ­ Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2001. 4. Ballard C.L., «The Marginal Efficiency Cost of Redistribution», The American Economic Review, vol. 78, iss. 5, (Dec., 1988), pp. 1019-1033. 5. Barrett, C R, and Maurice Salles. «On a Generalisation of the Gini Coefficient.» Mathematical Social Sciences 30.3 (1995): 235-44. 6. Bartolomew D.J., «Stochastic Models for Social Processes», Wiley, 1976, p. 24. 7. Dasgupta, P., A. Sen, and D. Starret. «Notes on the Measurement of Inequality.» Journal of Economic Theory 6.2 (1973): 180-87. 8. Kakwani N.C., «Applications of Lorenz Curves in Economic Analysis», Econometrica, vol. 45 (April 1977), pp. 719 ­727. 9. Lambert, P., and J Richard Aronson. «Inequality Decomposition Analysis and the Gini Coefficient Revisited.» Economic Journal 103.420 (1993): 1221-27. 10. Lehman E., «Testing Statistical Hypotheses», Wiley, 1959. 11. Merton, R. K., A. S. Rossi. «Contributions to the Theory of Reference Group Behaviour.» Social Theory and Social Structure. Ed. R.K. Merton. Glencoe, 1957. 12. Milanovic, Branko. «The Gini-Type Functions: An Alternative Derivation.» Bulletin of Economic Research 46.1 (1994): 81­90. 13. Mincer, J. (1974), «Schooling Experience and Earnings», Columbia University Press, N.Y. 14. Mirrlees J., «An Exploration in the Theory of Optimal Income Taxation», Review of Economic Studies, vol. 38, 1971, pp. 175-208. 15. Myles G., «Public Economics». ­ Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995. 16. Roshin S., Razumova T., «Secondary employment in Russia: modeling of the labor supply», 02/07, EERC, 2002. 17. Sabirianova K., «The Great Human Capital Reallocation. A Study of Occupational Mobility in Transitional Russia», WP 2K/11, EERC, 2000. 18. Saez E., «Using Elasticities to Derive Optimal Income Tax Rates», Review of Economic Studies, 2001, vol. 68, pp. 205-229. 19. Salanie, B., «The Economics of Taxation», The MIT Press, 2003. 20. Sen, A. K. On Economic Inequality. Oxford Clarendon Press, 1973. 21. Shorrocks, A. F. «Transfer Sensitive Inequality Measures.» Review of Economic Studies LIV (1987): 485-97. 22. Slemrod J., «Optimal Taxation and Optimal Tax Systems», 1990, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 157-178. 23. Zee H. ed., «Tax Policy Handbook», Tax Policy Division, Fiscal Affair Department, IMF, Washington, D.C., 1995. 24. Zoli, C., «Intersecting Generalized Lorenz Curves and the Gini Index.» Social Choice and Welfare 16.2 (1999): 183-96.

© 2005

11